The idea of socially-oriented business is not new, although Nobel Peace laureate Muhammad Yunus has certainly given an enormous impetus to it by his articulate branding of it as “social business”. The reason his campaign has caught so much public attention is perhaps its timing. Global capitalism, driven by the singular pursuit of profit, has in recent times exposed some of the worst brutalities of the system – repeated global financial meltdown, the increasing concentration of wealth and the unmitigated environmental damage associated with the looming threat of climate change. French

Global capitalism, driven by the singular pursuit of profit, has in recent times exposed some of the worst brutalities of the system – repeated global financial meltdown, the increasing concentration of wealth and the     unmitigated environmental damage associated with the looming threat of climate change

economist Thomas Piketty’s convincing analysis in his recent best-selling book Capital in the Twenty-First Century as to why the current capitalist system will lead to an unabated process of wealth concentration has only helped to add fuel to the fire of public discontent. It is not surprising that the global business community is eager to embrace the idea of social business, at least in its public posture, almost as a penance for the sins that have been committed.

In the world of academia, while the business schools in many top universities worldwide are setting up dedicated chairs to offer courses on social business, the response from the mainstream economics is at best lukewarm. Why? First, the idea of social business is still too fuzzy for an academic discipline that claims the status of a science. Muhammad Yunus describes it as a business which has social mission rather than profit-seeking as its main purpose and the owners of which do not earn any dividend from profit (Yunus 2007). That definition may fit a wide range of business models including, for example, many co-operative enterprises, so that it may be easier to say which business does not qualify than which one actually does so as a social business.
Second, while admitting that many market distortions do exist, economists are accustomed to the elegant theorising of the efficiency of the market economy that is rooted in the premise of self- seeking behaviour and the “profit motive”, and this tradition has continued ever since Adam Smith famously remarked that we owed our breakfast not to the benevolence of the baker and the butcher but their attending to self- interest. Yet, this need not be so. According to a long-forgotten strand of economic theorising, the success of a competitive free- enterprise economy can be shown to depend on people pursuing self- chosen interest, which can be altruistic or anything else (Winter, Jr 1969). These results are, however, derived under highly restrictive conditions; but one may argue that the assumptions underlying the welfare economics of competitive market economy are themselves far removed from reality and serve only as a point of departure. It was also once argued by some economists, for example, that the loyalty of the Japanese workers to his firm and to his co- workers, rather than individual self-seeking, was the key to the success of Japanese economy.
Incorporating social objectives in the working of the market economy should not be therefore altogether new to economic theorising.
In the real world of the market economy, it is now the generally accepted view that private business must exercise some measure of social responsibility beyond looking after shareholder interests. The question is how to do it best. Modern-day smart CEOs worldwide know that strategic spending on Corporate Social Responsibility (CSR) activities can be in the long-run business interest of their firms.
However, the phenomenon is reversed in the case of a social business, which takes advantage of viable business models while pursuing its overriding social goals. Indeed, an advantage of social business over conventional corporate philanthropy, as argued by Muhammad Yunus, is that once an investment is made in a social business its benefits will continue over the years while companies have to allocate funds annually for their CSR activities. This is similar to the advantage that a revolving fund for a microcredit programme may have over annual transfers to the poor under social safety net programmes. It is no coincidence that Yunus happens to be the pioneer of both microcredit and social business.
There is another promising way of reconciling the idea of social business with mainstream economic thinking. A social business is expected to achieve its social objectives by producing some socially-oriented products or services that are not supplied by profit-oriented businesses.
Examples may include marketing products at affordable prices specifically needed by the poor or promoting some environment- friendly or employment generating technology. These products and services are supposed to have what economists call “public good” characteristics; that is, their benefits extend beyond what would be otherwise reflected in the market demand and business profits. Because of the absence of the compulsion of profit maximisation, an implicit subsidy is involved when such products or services are produced and supplied by social businesses; only the subsidies in this case come not from the public exchequer but from foregone business profits.
Such subsidies can be justified in economic theory as a legitimate means of correcting market distortions and deficiencies. This line of reasoning can in fact be a more fruitful way of conceptualising social business instead of either trying to fit it in the grand scheme of the theory of competitive market equilibrium or attempting to reconstruct the entire logic of the profit-oriented market economy.
Perhaps a more relevant concern about social businesses is to do with the informational problem that may arise from their not being able to take full advantage of market signals in making decisions about prices and products. The informational deficiency may arise in perceiving what is good for society while not necessarily maximising profit as allowed by the market. Prices and profits, resulting from self-interested behaviour, serve a useful signalling function, since the interests of each person are best known by the person herself or himself. As Amartya Sen aptly puts it, “Doing good is not an easy matter with informational deficiency” (Sen 1984). One has to only recollect O Henry’s story ‘The Gift of the Magi’ to see how the pursuit of altruism can lead to frustration. A safeguard against social businesses not messing up the market mechanism is, however, provided by the stipulation of running the businesses at least on a no- loss basis, which  provides a bottom line for using the market as a disciplining force.
Overall, it may be more useful to judge the comparative merits of non-profit-maximising behaviour of social businesses in particular practical contexts rather than in terms of any given notion of efficiency or optimality of market mechanism.
The problem of informational deficiency is also linked to business risks. Private capitalists or their financiers take risks while investing in new business ventures. They are willing to undertake the risk of business failure because of the lure of earning profits; in fact, the riskier the investment, the higher are usually the expected returns from profits. Donors and philanthropists, however, may feel less comfortable with the idea that the social businesses they are investing in may, in some cases, fail to deliver the goods, and they may therefore like to see strict pre- project scrutiny in place. For example, can enough market segmentation be ensured so that the benefits from the products and services intended for the poor do not go to non-poor consumers? Or, given the “public good” characteristics of these products and services, will there be a need for social campaigns to create demand? Moreover, while profits and shareholder dividends are taken as performance yardsticks of profit-motivated businesses, it will be difficult to find one such single measure of success for a social business, so that the performance of each one has to be evaluated in terms of meeting its particular avowed social objectives. A possible approach may be to examine the social relevance of the project in a broader context rather than focusing on any narrowly interpreted impact assessment.
How far the social business campaign can create an impact will perhaps depend to a large measure on the resolution of these issues. Motivating the institutions and individuals with enough capital to embrace the idea of course remains a more fundamental challenge. n
REFERENCES
Sen, Amartya (1984): “The profit motive”, chapter 3, in Resources, Values and Development, New Delhi: Oxford University Press.
Winter, Jr, S. G. (1969): “A simple remark on the second optimality theorem of welfare economics”, Journal of Economic Theory. 1 (1969).
Yunus, Muhammad: (2007), “Social business” (accessed from the website of the Yunus Centre: http://www.muhammadyunus.org/index.php/social-
business/social-business.

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *